In article are considered features of «productive» function of the state as economic subject. Need and expediency of the state production of the net public benefits is most obvious. Not excludability is absolutely insuperable to them, and obviously there is no opportunity to replace expenses of the state coercion, if they are rather high, expenses on creation of a market mechanism of restriction of access to this benefit for «hare». When consumption is absolutely noncompetitive, price quotation of public goods or service in Pareto principle is inefficient as consumption of additional unit of the benefit brings benefit to the consumer without any expenses. Price quotation will reduce consumption, having caused under exploitation of the public benefits and a dead loss of usefulness. When the supply of net public goods through the market is possible, it won't provide achievement of the best (optimum) level of production. Result of research of authors is detection of features of «productive» function of the state on the example of the Republic of Kazakhstan, and also the problems which arose recently connected with the researched subject.
Statement of a problem. The condition and dynamics of the sphere of production as initial stage of a reproduction cycle predetermines proportions and development of its other phases. It demands active economic participation of the state in this sphere, in particular, through realization of a «productive» component of production function.
Productive function is a form of manifestation of economic behavior of the state in the production sphere for the purpose of ensuring its balance. Allocate two effects of this function: first, productive function in pure form, being shown in direct state production of the public and private benefits; secondly, the mediated productive function consisting in indirect impact on motivation and behavior of private producers.
Net productive function of the state is realized through production of the public benefits in state sector of economy. It is possible to prove need of the state production of the public benefits through detection of their specifics.
Analysis of the last researches and publications
The theoretical bases of analysis of production of the public benefits was laid within the neoclassical theory of welfare. Theoretical bases of production of the public benefits and positive outer effects were created in works of representatives of the theory of welfare, such as N.Kaldor, E. Lindal, A. Marshall, V. Pareto, A. Pigou, P. Samuelson, T. Scitovsky, J. Hicks, H. Hotelling.
The theory of the public benefits is connected with the theory of public sector of economy in which the state is researched as the specific subject of modern economy. Questions of the theory of the public benefits were taken up by such authors as E. Atkinson, J. Stiglitz, J. Buchanan, J. Dupuy, R. Musgrave, M. Olson, K. Arrow. Bases of the theory of a budget federalism as systems of differentiation of powers on provision of the public benefits are pledged in works of D. Kings, R. Musgrave, W. Oates.
ІІІ. Article purpose
Many theoretical and practical questions of the public benefits, including problem of increase of efficiency of their production is one of the most perspective directions of modern economic science as many theoretical and applied aspects didn't gain due development yet. In particular, in case of all importance of the conducted researches there is no constructive classification of the public benefits. The theoretical and practical importance of studying of these problems, need of application of new approaches also determined a choice of a subject of research, the purposes and tasks of work.
Main results of research
The concept of the public benefits was put forward by P. Samuelson in 1954 and further is developed by R. Musgrave in the theory of socially significant (deserved) benefit in the late fifties [1, 2]. P. Samuelson marked out two main properties of the public benefit - non-competitiveness in consumption and non excludability.
Criteria of competition and non-competition, excludability and non excludability allow drawing a clear line between the net private and net public benefit. The first represents a competition and excludability combination, and the second is characterized at the same time by two properties – absolute non-competitiveness and not excludability. Considered polar situations can be described as follows: for net private goods equality takes place:
∑ Xi = X,. (1)
h=1
where Xih — consumption of i-goods by h-household; Xi — aggregate supply of i-good.
Contrary to it for net public goods
Xih = Xi . at any h. (2)
The net public benefit and the net private benefit are extreme points of a scale of the economic benefits. Between them there are much more often the mixed different benefits meeting in reality which proximity to this or that pole is defined by prevalence of properties of private or public goods. The mixed public benefit unlike pure is the excluded benefit of joint consumption with selectivity. alternativeness of its use. with decrease of its consumption.
The following group of the public benefits is also possible taking into account a set of the corresponding parameters (Table 1).
Specifics of the public benefits (pure and mixed) consist in the following: the external effect has impact not only on the direct participants of activity connected with this benefit. but also extends on foreign faces. generating a so-called problem of «free rider». The market mechanism effectively works to the economic benefits only on condition that their external effect can be controlled by participants of the transaction connected with this benefit.
In a situation with the public benefits ways and methods of internalization of external effects. solutions of the problem of «free riders» are defined by the volume and intensity of external influence. its positive or negative character. possibility of divisibility of these or those public benefits. degree of their excludability and alternativeness in consumption. and also possibility of quantitative change of an external effect. If scales of external effect are insignificant and a circle of subjects is small. and production of this public benefit and its collateral external action can be taken without participation of the state under control by direct participants of the economic transaction or self-governed public organization. If the problem of «hare» gains wide scope. systematic underproduction of the public benefits is formed. and there is a situation at which delivery of the benefit has to be carried out by the state.
Providing adequate output of the pure public benefits possibly only at public and obligatory approach to formation of funds for their creation by means of the compulsory state taxation. At domination of free business the market economy isn't democratic. The state independently defines standard item of the public benefits and appoints taxes. without reckoning with. whether individuals want to have these goods and services in such quantities or not. Therefore it is necessary to aspire that all pure public benefits delivered to the individual. corresponded to his compelled contribution.
Problem in that: the state has to define output of the pure public benefits. and also quantitative range of the specific taxpayers bringing means for consumption. «Therefore the political mechanism steps on the stage as substitute of the market and determinant of the directions of action of the state coercion» [3].
Taxpayers at the same time are also voters; the effective instrument of tax regulation of production of the pure public benefits is the electoral system by means of which society expresses the preferences to elected representatives in authorities depending on their positions. Decision-making by vote replaces detection of preferences through a market mechanism that is the public choice in public sector carries out a certain selfcorrecting function. as a consumer choice – in the private sector. The self-correcting effect of a public choice of subjects is stronger. than the level of development of political democracy is higher. Then at the certain individual is reduced the gap distance between its role of the taxpayer and a role of the consumer of the net public benefit.
The market mechanism isn't capable to function effectively in the sphere of production of the mixed public benefits, as socially significant benefit (the deserved benefit) and the quasi public benefit.
Socially significant benefit synthesizes properties of the private excluded benefit and property of the public benefit through considerable positive external effect. Such benefits consist from education, health care, culture, services of other branches of the welfare sphere.
The specific nature of the deserved benefit, multi composite character of an external effect, long term of its influence and lack of accurate contours of influence create an objective basis for emergence of contradictions between the current individual and long-term public preferences in consumption of such benefits. It is necessary a certain state intervention for permission of this collision in favor of public preferences and introduction of obligation of consumption of socially significant goods and services. Otherwise at freedom of a consumer choice there are no guarantees that citizens won't prefer to spend funds for the current consumption, but they don't spend funds for the deserved benefits [4].
The most serious insolvency of the market causing emergence of the state production of the mixed benefits arises when the markets aren't competitive. The main reason acts existence of growing economy at production scales. In this situation economic efficiency demands limited number of producers. The branch in which economy growth at scales is so considerable, functions only one firm, is natural monopoly.
The benefits made in branches of natural monopoly, are the quasi public benefits. In the excluded benefits of joint consumption there are more than properties of private goods and much less characteristic properties of the public benefit. Specifics of these branches are in large scale of production and a considerable capital intensity that makes high demands of the volume of the initial capital for the accession to these branches of new competitors. The characteristic transmission of technologies for branches of natural monopoly (network type of production) excludes infrastructure duplication on providing the population with this production, doing technically impossible existence of the competitive environment.
The state intervention to the sphere of production of the quasi public benefits consists that private firms pursue the aim of maximizing own profit, instead of welfare of the nation that conducts to inefficient distribution of resources. The state chooses one of two possible options of behavior without having opportunity to eliminate zones of natural monopoly without efficiency loss: or to fill these zones with the enterprises of public sector, or to use measures of indirect regulation of activity of the monopolist [5].
The state, functioning as the producer in the natural and monopoly environment, is guided by other principles of managing, than private firms. It allows to use the sphere of the state delivered quasi public benefits for the solution of strategic economic tasks, increases of profitability of private enterprise. The monopoly profit isn't the paramount purpose of activity of the state as producer of the quasi public benefits. It became the supplier of cheap services (in particular, transport, post and cable), energy resources (coal -, gas -, oil production, electricity generation), reducing expenditures in the private sector.
If scales of external effect are insignificant also the range of market agents is small, other kinds of the mixed public benefits it isn't required direct state intervention. Collateral external influence can be without state participation, is internalized by self-governed public organization or direct participants of the transaction on mixed the benefits.
Approximate idea of the high possible scales of implementation by the state of direct productive function can be received on the basis of data on specific expenditures on production of the public benefits in gross domestic product of the developed countries given in Table 2.
Table 2 shows the considered period in the USA where the share of the public expenditures in gross domestic product for the net public benefits averages 16,1%; for socially significant benefits with inclusion of social transfer payments - 17,9%; for the quasi-public benefits - 5,5%. In Germany during the same period for the pure public benefits was spent 15,1% of gross domestic product; for socially significant benefits (including social transfers) - 25,1%; for actually socially significant benefits - 13,3%; for the quasi-public benefits - 5,8 percent. The similar picture was observed in other industrial countries. These data allow to reveal priorities in realization by the state of productive function in net form: on the first place are socially significant benefits, on the second are net public goods and services, on the third place are quasi-public and other types of the public benefits.
Table 2 The Share of the Public Expenditures on Production of the Public Benefits
in Gross Domestic Product of the Developed Countries from 1950 to 2015, %
Country |
Years |
Total |
Net public benefits |
Social benefits |
Quasipublic benefits |
|||||
Management |
Defense |
Order protection |
Total |
Education |
Health care |
Social transfers |
||||
1950 |
24,9 |
0,8 |
13,1 |
0,5 |
7,0 |
3,2 |
0,5 |
3,2 |
3,5 |
|
1980 |
33,5 |
1,5 |
8,5 |
1,3 |
18,2 |
6,6 |
1,5 |
10,1 |
4,0 |
|
USA |
1990 |
35,0 |
1,6 |
6,9 |
1,5 |
19,0 |
6,9 |
1,6 |
10,5 |
6,0 |
2000 |
35,7 |
1,7 |
4,7 |
1,6 |
20,8 |
7,2 |
1,9 |
10,7 |
6,9 |
|
2015 |
36,5 |
1,0 |
2,6 |
1,4 |
24,6 |
7,7 |
2,3 |
14,6 |
6,9 |
|
1950 |
28,4 |
1,9 |
4,3 |
1,4 |
18,4 |
2,7 |
3,5 |
12,2 |
2,4 |
|
1980 |
42,4 |
3,2 |
4,4 |
2,4 |
25,6 |
4,8 |
6,8 |
14,0 |
6,8 |
|
Germany |
1990 |
42,9 |
3,2 |
4,2 |
2,6 |
26,5 |
5,1 |
7,1 |
14,1 |
6,7 |
2000 |
42,9 |
3,5 |
4,0 |
2,7 |
27,1 |
5,4 |
7,2 |
14,5 |
5,6 |
|
2015 |
42,8 |
2,6 |
2,5 |
2,5 |
27,7 |
5,7 |
7,5 |
14,5 |
7,5 |
|
1950 |
31,4 |
2,0 |
7,8 |
0,8 |
19,6 |
4,7 |
2,4 |
12,5 |
1,2 |
|
1980 |
45,3 |
2,8 |
5,0 |
1,7 |
32,6 |
8,3 |
4,4 |
19,9 |
3,3 |
|
France |
1990 |
47,2 |
3,5 |
5,7 |
1,3 |
33,5 |
8,7 |
4,8 |
20,0 |
3,3 |
2000 |
47,5 |
3,3 |
4,7 |
1,4 |
34,3 |
8,7 |
5,1 |
20,5 |
3,8 |
|
2015 |
45,5 |
2,5 |
3,0 |
1,3 |
34,8 |
8,8 |
5,6 |
20,5 |
3,8 |
|
1950 |
32,1 |
1,5 |
4,6 |
1,5 |
17,9 |
5,1 |
5,1 |
7,7 |
6,4 |
|
Great Britain |
1980 |
40,6 |
1,9 |
6,9 |
2,5 |
22,5 |
6,9 |
6,9 |
8,8 |
6,9 |
1990 |
42,9 |
1,9 |
6,7 |
2,4 |
25,6 |
6,9 |
6,9 |
11,9 |
6,3 |
|
2000 |
43,1 |
2,0 |
5,7 |
2,4 |
26,8 |
7,0 |
7,3 |
12,5 |
6,1 |
|
2015 |
43,4 |
1,7 |
3,5 |
2,3 |
29,8 |
7,2 |
8,1 |
14,5 |
6,1 |
|
1950 |
22,5 |
1,5 |
3,0 |
1,5 |
14,5 |
3,5 |
3,0 |
8,0 |
2,0 |
|
1980 |
38,1 |
2,8 |
3,2 |
2,8 |
24,7 |
6,3 |
5,1 |
13,3 |
4,5 |
|
Italy |
1990 |
47,9 |
3,7 |
3,7 |
3,2 |
31,8 |
7,4 |
6,5 |
18,0 |
5,5 |
2000 |
49,0 |
3,6 |
3,2 |
3,2 |
34,3 |
7,2 |
6,5 |
20,6 |
4,8 |
|
2015 |
45,5 |
2,8 |
2,0 |
2,8 |
33,1 |
6,7 |
6,5 |
19,8 |
4,8 |
|
1950 |
13,2 |
1,6 |
1,1 |
1,6 |
6,8 |
3,2 |
0,5 |
3,2 |
2,1 |
|
1980 |
25,0 |
1,9 |
1,0 |
1,9 |
16,2 |
5,4 |
0,6 |
10,3 |
3,9 |
|
Japan |
1990 |
26,9 |
2,1 |
1,0 |
2,1 |
18,4 |
5,6 |
0,7 |
12,0 |
3,4 |
2000 |
27,2 |
2,0 |
1,0 |
2,0 |
18,8 |
5,6 |
0,8 |
12,4 |
3,3 |
|
2015 |
29,7 |
1,4 |
0,9 |
2,0 |
21,8 |
5,7 |
1,2 |
14,9 |
3,7 |
Note. Source: It is made by the author on a source [6].
For the Kazakhstan economy are characteristic the same tendencies concerning the directions of realization by the state of direct productive function, as for the countries with normally functioning mixed economy (it is visible from Table 3).
Table 3 Dynamics of Expenditures of the State Budget of the Republic of Kazakhstan, in 2010-2016, billion tenge
Expenditures |
2010 |
2011 |
2012 |
2013 |
2014 |
2015 |
2016 |
Deflection, 2016 \ 2015 |
|
Billion tenge |
θ/ % |
||||||||
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
8 |
9 |
10 |
The state services of general character |
225 |
296 |
326 |
382 |
484 |
697 |
419 |
-278 |
60,1 |
Defense |
221 |
265 |
241 |
397 |
432 |
454 |
453 |
-1 |
99,8 |
Continuation of Table 3
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
8 |
9 |
10 |
Public order, safety, legal, judicial, criminal and executive activity |
369 |
448 |
558 |
608 |
601 |
557 |
455 |
-102 |
81,7 |
Education |
769 |
987 |
1210 |
1237 |
1359 |
1365 |
531 |
-834 |
38,9 |
Health care |
551 |
626 |
731 |
795 |
856 |
864 |
790 |
-74 |
91,4 |
Social aid and social security |
905 |
1134 |
1239 |
1360 |
1549 |
1713 |
1896 |
183 |
110,7 |
Housing and communal services |
334 |
389 |
439 |
472 |
555 |
443 |
158 |
-285 |
35,7 |
Culture, sport, tourism and information environment |
228 |
202 |
223 |
258 |
298 |
294 |
116 |
-178 |
39,5 |
Fuel and energy complex and subsurface use |
80 |
112 |
127 |
120 |
129 |
112 |
63 |
-49 |
56,25 |
Agriculture, water, forest, the fishery, especially protected natural territories, environmental protection and fauna, the land relations |
207 |
271 |
293 |
259 |
349 |
376 |
192 |
-184 |
51,1 |
Industry, architectural, townplanning and construction activity |
28 |
25 |
26 |
32 |
43 |
62 |
10 |
-52 |
16,1 |
Transport and communication |
391 |
449 |
482 |
511 |
614 |
682 |
560 |
-122 |
82,1 |
Other |
68 |
97 |
144 |
243 |
292 |
310 |
1015 |
705 |
327,4 |
Debt services |
95 |
122 |
131 |
178 |
233 |
297 |
551 |
254 |
185,5 |
Total |
4471 |
5423 |
6269 |
6853 |
7792 |
8227 |
8045 |
-182 |
97,8 |
Note. Source: It is made by the author on a source [6, 7
So, priorities are placed as follows in implementation of pure productive function by the domestic state: other expenditures is on the first place - on the average 13% of gross domestic product. Debt services averaging 6,8 percent from gross domestic product is on the second place. At last, the social aid and social security by the state, averaging 2,3 percent from gross domestic product is on the third place.
The sphere of the pure public benefits approximately corresponds to minimum possible scales of implementation of direct productive function by the state, and the sphere of the mixed public benefits gives an idea of admissible limits of its interventionism, being the arena of cooperation and the competition to the private sector [8]. In the second situation is admissible and expedient statement of a question of minimization of the state participation in creation and financing of the mixed public benefits. If property of non excludability is shown, it makes sense to consider possibilities of use of market mechanisms and a private initiative. If borders of not rivalry are rather narrow, the state production of the mixed public benefits should be focused mainly on local levels and to use mechanisms of voluntary collective actions.
V. Conclusions
In all countries the public sector is a dual, inconsistent institutional formation. It personifies two beginnings: the market - based on equivalence of an exchange, onerousness, property right alienation, purchase and sale, and non-market - based on nonequivalence, gratuitousness, the uncertain specification of the property rights, non-market mechanisms of distribution of resources. The duality of the economic nature of public sector is a source of inefficient use of economic resources. This dualism in production of the public benefits causes the necessity of effective legislative regulation of this sector for the purpose of providing conditions for rationalization of use of economic resources in creation of such benefits.
The state carries out productive function in the pure and mediated forms. Dominating economic effect in its realization is direct production of net public, socially significant, quasi public and private benefits within public sector of economy.
As a whole. productive function of the state is aimed at providing balance of a social production. Influence on its qualitative and proliferation is carried out through an investment component of production function of the state.
References
- Samuelson, P.A. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 36, 4, 387–389. (Nov., 1954). Cambridge: The MIT Press: National Bureau of Economic Research. Retrieved from http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0034-6535%28195411%2936%3A4%3C387%3ATPTOPE%3E2.0.CO%3B2-A.
- Musgrave, R.A. (1959). Classics in the Theory of Public Finance. The American Economic Review, Vol. 49, 5 (Dec., 1959), 1018–1029. Harvard University: American Economic Association. Retrieved from http://www.jstor.org/stable/1813080.
- Olson, M. (1964) The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups (Harvard Economic Studies 124). Cambridge: Harvard University Press. sisphd.wikispaces.com. Retrieved from http://sisphd.wikispaces.com/file/view/Olson+ COLLECTIVE-ACTION+1A.PDF.
- Coase, R. H. (1991). Firma, rynok i pravo [The Firm, the Market and the Law]. New-York: Teletext ∣in Russian].
- Akhinov, G.A., & Zhiltsov, E.N. (2008). Ekonomika Obshchestvennoho sektora [Economy of public sector]. Moscow: Izdatelstvo MHU ∣in Russian].
- Kudrov, V. (2002). Hosudarstvo i economika: meniaiushcheеsia ravnovesie [State and economy: changing balance]. Problemy teorii i praktiki upravleniia – Problems of the theory and practice of management, 3, 8–13 ∣in Russian].
- The budget for all. Report. (2016, January). Astana. minfin.gov.kz. Retrieved from http://www.minfin.gov.kz:81/BOE/OpenDocument/1507271855/OpenDocument/opendoc/openDocument.faces?logonSuccessful=tru e&shareId=0&bttoken=MDAwREo5UGdeOzlFUFZWZzFcPjtYT29aZkdKY2tRNzAEQ&iDocID=AWw85R9HEAlHiPPN4ipp0lg &token=STANDBO.emf.minfin.kz%3A6400%40826265JN3ssuibliUZZgdRqEduvsv826264JJgJ6cllvbqzFuGDoTyc1FM&sIDType =CUID&isApplication=true&appKind=OpenDocument.
- Marshall, A. (1890). The principles of Economics (Macmillan and Co., Ltd.). London: Macmillan and Co., Ltd. econlib.org. Retrieved from http://www.econlib.org/library/Marshall/marP.html.